Distribution and Redistribution in Post-Industrial Democracies

نویسندگان

  • David Bradley
  • Evelyne Huber
  • Stephanie Moller
  • Francois Nielsen
  • John Stephens
چکیده

Distributive Processes in Post-Industrial Democracies David Bradley, Evelyne Huber, Stephanie Moller, Francois Nielsen, and John Stephens; University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill This paper analyzes the processes of distribution and redistribution in post-industrial democracies. We combine a pooled time series data base on welfare state effort and its determinants assembled by Huber, Ragin, and Stephens (1997) with data on income distribution assembled in the Luxembourg Income Survey (LIS) archive. In the case of the LIS data, we re-calculate the micro-data in order to remove the distorting influence of pensioners on pre-tax, pre transfer income distribution. We examine the determinants of three dependent variables: pre-tax, pre-transfer income inequality, posttax, post transfer income inequality and the proportional reduction in inequality from pre to post tax and transfer inequality. We hypothesized that pre-tax, pre-transfer income inequality would be determined by labor market institutions (union density, bargaining centralization), labor market conditions (unemployment), and economic structures (postindustrialism, third world imports). We hypothesized that the reduction in inequality would be determined by political configurations: directly by left government and indirectly via their effect on welfare state generosity by left government and Christian democratic government. Post tax and transfer income inequality was hypothesized to be a product of the combination of labor market variables and political variables. The results broadly confirms our hypotheses and the overall fit is very good (R =.56 to .80). Other than the level of economic development and peace, arguably no economic or political outcome is more consequential to the quality of life of the members of a society than the distribution of disposable income. In this article, we analyze pooled time series data which shed light on the age-old question of politics “who gets what, when, and how” for the case of complex post-industrial democracies with an emphasis on the “who, what, and how.” We seek to understand HOW different social strata (WHO) get WHAT share of income. Specifically, we investigate to what extent distribution and redistribution are driven by demographic and economic or by institutional and political variables. This is important not only from a theoretical point of view, but also from the point of view of political practice. Economic and demographic factors are extremely difficult to manipulate, and so are certain institutions, such as labor market institutions. In contrast, partisan composition of government and tax and transfer policies are more amenable to political choice. Thus, if we can demonstrate that partisan composition of government and tax and transfer policies indeed play a crucial role in redistributing resources in society, we lay the responsibility for the degree of inequality in access to material resources squarely on the shoulders of political leaders. Given that the degree to which governments redistribute income is arguably one of the most consequential outcomes of the political process for citizens' living conditions, it is surprising that there have been so few studies which attempt to explain variation across advanced industrial societies in distributive outcomes and the redistribution process. One might suppose that this topic would have been a major preoccupation of the comparative welfare states literature, but only a handful of cross national studies of the determinants of distributive outcomes have been produced, compared to literally hundreds of studies of social spending. No study has ever attempted to account for variations in the degree to which governments redistribute income. This is odd given that, as Esping-Andersen (1990) observes, governments do not spend money just to spend money but rather to affect an outcome and certainly one of the most important political outcomes is redistribution. The answer to the paradox of why such important processes have been so little studied is simple: lack of comparable data on an adequate number of cases. For example, the OECD sponsored study by Sawyer (1976) was only able to develop "reasonably comparable" data for ten countries and, by the standards of the Luxembourg Income Survey (LIS), Sawyer's figures were of questionable comparability. The first wave of LIS studies improved comparability greatly and, unlike the Sawyer study, allowed the researcher to measure how much of the final distributive outcome was due to governmental redistribution (e.g. see Mitchell 1991). However, the number of cases, ten to twelve, was far too small to allow multivariate statistical analyses of the causes of variation in distributive and redistributive processes. Fortunately, the subsequent 1 Before the publication of Sawyer (1976), several scholars used the Paukert (1973) income distribution data (e.g. see Hewitt 1977, Cameron 1976, Stephens 1976). After the Sawyer study revealed the incomparability of much of these data, Stephens (1979) used the Sawyer data but dropped multiple regression for simple correlation due to the small number of cases, while Cameron (1978) dropped the income distribution section of the earlier APSA paper. Distribution and Redistribution, draft 5/14/01 2 development of the LIS data archive expanding of the number of countries covered and the time points for which there is available data – now makes such analyses possible. In this article, we examine the determinants of distributive and redistributive processes in post-industrial democracies using three measures calculated from the LIS data as dependent variables: pre-tax, pre-transfer income distribution, posttax, post transfer income distribution and the proportional reduction in inequality from pre to post tax and transfer inequality. We hypothesize that the measures of market and final income distribution and of reduction in inequality will be determined by different combinations of labor market institutions (union density, bargaining centralization), labor market conditions (unemployment), economic structures (post-industrialism, third world imports), and political configurations (left government and Christian democratic government). We expect political configurations to shape resdistribution both directly and indirectly via their effect on welfare state generosity. Literature and Hypotheses The dates and countries of the available LIS studies strongly shape the literature and the range of hypotheses relevant to our analysis. First, since one of our purposes is to examine the impact of the welfare state on redistribution, we limit our study to the 18 advanced industrial countries that have a population of one million or more and have been democracies since World War II. This is the usual universe of cases studied in quantitative studies of the development of the welfare state. There are LIS studies available for 16 of these countries, 14 of which are included in this study. Second, the earliest LIS studies date back to the late 1960s, and 54 of the 61 surveys were done after 1975. Thus, these countries were in transition from industrialism to post industrialism, which makes a large body of literature on income distribution, notably work on the inverted U-shaped Kuznets curve relating inequality with economic development (e.g. see Kuznets 1955; Nielsen 1994; Nielsen and Alderson 1995 and literature therein) and World System and dependency studies (e.g. see Bornschier and Chase-Dunn 1985; Alderson and Nielsen 1999 and literature therein) irrelevant for our study. We draw primarily on the recent literature on the comparative political economy of the welfare state and labor market institutions for our main hypotheses. However, we begin by reviewing the two recent analyses of pooled cross sections and times series data on income inequality in advanced capitalist democracies in order to situate our own work, Gustafsson and Johanson (1999) and Alderson and Nielsen (2001). Both confirm Stephens' (1979) finding that union organization is a strong determinant of income distribution, high levels of unionization being associated with less inequality. In addition, Gustaffson and Johanson find strong positive effects of deindustrialization and youth proportion of the population on inequality and significant but more modest negative ones of public sector size. Alderson and Nielsen find strong positive effects of 2 The one Austrian LIS survey and the one Irish survey were excluded due to missing data. Distribution and Redistribution, draft 5/14/01 3 agricultural employment and negative ones of Esping-Andersen's decommodification index on inequality and more modest positive ones for third world imports and direct investment outflow. Our study differs from these two studies in two important ways. First, we break down the distributive process into two stages and analyze the determinants of the pre tax and transfer (or market) income inequality and the reduction in inequality separately. Though we do provide an analysis of post tax and transfer income inequality in order to compare our findings with these two studies, our focus is on the two distinct stages rather than the final outcome. Second, we take advantage of the fact the LIS micro data are available for analysis, and we calculate our own measures of the dependent variable. Most importantly we limit our analysis to the working age population, which allows us both to eliminate the distortion in measures of reduction in inequality created by the inclusion of the aged population (see below) and to measure cross income group (rather than age group) distribution and redistribution more precisely. This is crucial because it addresses one of the most prominent critiques of the welfare state made from a critical left view point, that welfare states are at best redistributive across age groups but not across classes. We draw our primary hypotheses from power resources theory and its extension, power constellation theory (Rueschemeyer, Stephens, and Stephens 1992, Huber and Stephens 2001), and from recent research on bargaining systems and wage dispersion. Neo-marxist power resources theory (Korpi 1983, Stephens 1979) and its predecessors (Lenski 1966: 316-25, also see Hewitt 1977) argue that distributive outcomes are a product of power relations in society. In advanced capitalist democracies, power resources theory predicts that variations in distribution are a product of variations in working class power; in union strength, socialist party strength, and left government. As we do here, Stephens (1979) breaks the distributive process into two stages. He argues that variations in pre tax and transfer income are products of variations in union strength. In his view, the size and structure of the welfare state determine the degree of governmental redistribution. On the basis of his crossnational analysis, he argues that there are two paths to high welfare state generosity, a catholic and a social democratic corporatist one. He argues that the social democratic corporatist one is much more redistributive. Huber and Stephens (2000, 2001) considerably refine this view, especially on the determinants of welfare state size and structure. In pooled time series analyses of annual data for 26 countries for 26 time points, they show that the main determinants of variation in eight different indicators of aspects of the welfare state are social democratic government, Christian democratic government, and constitutional structure veto points, with more modest effects of unemployment and female labor force participation. The availability of a number of veto points in a country’s constitutional structure depresses welfare state expansion because it enables relatively small groups to obstruct legislation. By the same token, it also slows welfare state retrenchment by enabling losers to block cut-backs. Christian democracy is more strongly related to transfers payments and transfer heavy measures of welfare state effort, while social democracy is more strongly related to measures tapping service provision. Based on a crossnational analysis of LIS Distribution and Redistribution, draft 5/14/01 4 data on 16 countries, Huber and Stephens (2001) offer the tentative conclusion that social democracy but not Christian democracy has an effect on government reduction in inequality and post tax and transfer inequality. Given the small sample size, they do not test for a full range of alternative causal and control variables. On the basis of these findings, then, we hypothesize that political composition of government affects redistribution indirectly through welfare state generosity, but that there remains a direct political effect on redistribution. Recent literature on wage bargaining institutions and wage dispersion argues that centralized bargaining results in less wage dispersion (e.g. see Iversen 1996, Wallerstein 1999, and Pontusson et al. forthcoming). Both Wallerstein's (1999) and Pontusson et al.'s (forthcoming) analyses of pooled time series data on wage inequality do show very strong effects of wage bargaining systems on wage dispersion among full time employed workers. Based on these studies, we expect to find at least moderately strong effects of bargaining centralization on pre tax and transfer household income distribution. Unemployment should increase pre tax and transfer inequality and, to the extent that welfare state benefits do not replace work income, it should also affect post tax and transfer inequality. The hypothesized effect of unemployment on the reduction in inequality is, at first blush, counterintuitive: To the extent that welfare state benefits replace work income, it should increase redistribution. That is, in the presence of unemployment benefits (which all of these countries have) and other income replacements for unemployed workers (which most of them have), higher unemployment will be associated with more redistribution, ceteris paribus. The literature on the impact of post industrialism and globalization on inequality suggests several additional hypotheses (Nielsen and Alderson 2001). The transition from an industrial to a service economy is associated with increasing inequality as wages are lower and more dispersed in the service sector due to the low levels of labor productivity in personal and social services (Bluestone and Harrison 1982). Imports from developing countries should increase wage dispersion as they put downward pressure on the wages of low skilled workers who work in industries competing with these imports (Wood 1994). Increased international capital flows and, to a lesser extent trade flows, have been hypothesized to increase inequality for a variety of reasons. Increased capital mobility increases the power of capital vis à vis government and labor, making it possible for capital to use the threat of exit to demand tax concessions from governments and wage concessions from organized labor. Competition with imports and for export markets enables capital to persuade labor to restrain wages in order to preserve jobs. 3 Note that our dependent variable is household income and includes the households of the unemployed. Thus, the inverse relationship between wage dispersion and unemployment noted by Wood 1994 and Esping-Anderson 2001 would not be expected in our data. They explain this inverse relationship with the argument that in countries offering high unemployment benefits, unemployed workers will be more likely to prefer unemployment (with attractive benefits) rather than accept low paying jobs, while in countries with few benefits workers have no other choice than accepting these low paying jobs Distribution and Redistribution, draft 5/14/01 5 Development, usually operationalized as GDP per capita in constant dollars, has been included as a causal variable in almost all studies of income distribution. For studies that include developing countries or long time series on advanced industrial countries stretching back into the early part of the twentieth century, the key hypothesis was the Kuznets inverted U curve. For their study of both industrializing and deindustrializing societies, Nielsen and Alderson (1995) hypothesize (and find) a U curve in which inequality continues to fall in mature industrial societies but then increases with the onset of post-industrialism and globalization (see also Alderson and Nielsen 2001). As we pointed out above, our sample of countries and time points falls into the postindustrial category, thus one would expect a trend to increasing inequality with rising per capita income. However, it is unclear that rising income per se independent of the associated processes of deindustrialization and globalization outlined in the previous paragraph should be associated with greater inequality. Considered as a labor market variable, female labor force participation has been hypothesized to both increase or decrease inequality by different authors (Thurow 1987; Cancian, Dantziger and Gottschalk 1995; Nielsen and Alderson 1997). To further complicate the picture, female labor force participation has been shown to result in political mobilization of women, in shifting preferences of women toward left parties, and in greater demands for welfare state transfers and services (Huber and Stephens 2000, 2001). Pulling these two literatures together, we hypothesize positive effects of female labor force participation on reduction of inequality and negative effects on income inequality, particularly post tax and transfer inequality. Following the lead of previous LIS researchers, we adjust household income for household size (see below). Thus, if there is a negative association between household income and fertility, as is often the case, there will be a positive association between the proportion of the population that are young and inequality. In closing, we note that many of the variables that have been hypothesized to affect income inequality have no necessary relationship to governmental reduction in inequality. Given the absence of a theoretical justification for their inclusion, we do not include per capita income, proportion young, third world imports, and post industrialism in our analysis of reduction in inequality. Measures of Dependent and Independent Variables The measures of inequality come from the Luxembourg Income Study (LIS) database, which provides the most comparable income and earnings data available 4 We should note that globalization is causally related to the development of the world economy but simply associated with (and not causally related to) rising per capita GDP in individual countries. Thus, for example, in the mid 1990s, economic actors and policy makers in the US and the UK are facing the same pressures from open financial markets despite quite different levels of per capita GDP. By contrast, post industrialization is primarily a property of the domestic economy, thus there is a stronger causal link between the development of the domestic economy and post industrialism than between domestic economic development and globalization. Distribution and Redistribution, draft 5/14/01 6 across a large number of OECD countries. LIS collects data from national microdata (i.e. survey data based on individual level data rather than macro aggregates) sources and harmonizes the data sets to make income comparisons across countries and over time possible. Currently, there are survey data available for 25 countries, and over time points ranging from 1 year to 7 years per country. LIS data are arranged by waves, with the first starting in the late 1970s and the most recent wave in the mid to late 1990s. There also exist historical data (pre-1979) for a handful of countries. The collection and harmonization of data in waves means that LIS data can be used to look at income trends, rather than single points in time only. The LIS surveys provide the best available comparable cross-national, over time data source for income in OECD countries. In a comparison of reported income data (from surveys, the source of LIS data) with external aggregates (e.g. national accounts, income tax data), the OECD found that ratios of survey based data to national accounts based data normally fall in the 80-90% range (OECD 1995). In other words, the advantages one gains by using survey data (i.e. detailed demographic information), rather than national accounts, does not seem to come at a high cost in terms of data quality for income. Even national microdata sources change over time, due to altering of the sampling method, question formulation, etc. The LIS project draws on a variety of microdata sources – income surveys, administrative and income tax records, panel studies, expenditure surveys, and labor force survey supplements – to create income and demographic variables at both the household and individual level. The income inequality figures published on the LIS web site and in the many publications using the LIS data are not adequate for our purposes, as they include pensioners, which distorts the pre tax and transfer inequality and exaggerates the reduction in equality, as mentioned above. In countries with comprehensive public pension systems, such as the Nordic countries, which give the pensioner a replacement rate which is often three quarters of his or her working income, pensioners make little other provision for retirement. For instance, in an analysis of LIS data, Mäkinen (1998) finds that 93% of Finns and 89% of Swedes are poor before transfers and only 4% and 2% are poor, respectively, after transfers are added in. Thus, pre tax income inequality (and poverty) will be artificially high and the reduction in equality also exaggerated. In order to avoid this distortion, we conducted our own analysis of the LIS micro data excluding those over 59 and under 25. This excludes most early pensioners and students as well, so the remaining population is clearly working age. We constructed three measures: pre tax and transfer inequality, post tax and transfer inequality, and reduction in inequality effected by taxes and transfers (see Tables 1 and 2). For our measure of inequality we chose the gini coefficient. The gini coefficient is a measure of income distribution based on plotting the share of households in a given setting (in this case a country) against the cumulative share of income. The gini coefficient ranges from zero to one. With complete equality in society (all 5 See http://www.lis.ceps.lu for a general introduction to the LIS database and a complete list of countries, years, and variables available in this rich data source. 6 To take one example, Mitchell calculates that taxes and transfers reduce inequality among the population of surveyed Swedes in 1981 by 53%, whereas our calculations for the population 25-59 show a 34% reduction in equality. Distribution and Redistribution, draft 5/14/01 7 households having an exactly equal share of income) the gini coefficient would equal zero; similarly, if one household held all the income the gini would equal one. A lower gini coefficient indicates greater equality. There are several choices facing users of microdata in terms of how to calculate income variables. As discussed above, we restrict our measure of inequality to households with a head aged 25 to 59 years old to reduce the distorting effects of pensioners and students on the distribution of income. The pre tax and transfer gini calculations are based on market income. This is the total income from wages and salaries, self-employment income, property income, and private pension income. The post tax and transfer gini is based on disposable personal income. This includes all market income, social transfers, and taxes. Both market income and disposable income figures were bottom coded at 1% of mean income adjusted for household size and composition. Because we are using an income concept based on households, adjustments had to be made for household size. Equivalence scales are used to adjust the number of persons in a household to an equivalent number of adults. If one chooses not to use an equivalence scale, one ignores the economies of scale resulting from sharing household expenses and assumes that each additional equivalent adult in a household has the same “cost” as other members of the household. We choose a commonly used scale of the square root of the number of persons in the household (see OECD 1995 for a discussion of equivalence scales). {Tables 1 and 2 about here} Our exclusion of pensioners and youth from the analysis has an additional great advantage from the point of view of the comparative welfare states literature. In critiques of the welfare state, it is often claimed that welfare states effect only life cycle redistributions of income and not redistribution across income classes. By limiting the analysis to the working age population, we assure that our measure does measure redistribution across income groups. As one can see from Table 2, the reduction in inequality effected by taxes and transfers is substantial and the cross national variation in the reduction is also great. Our proposed measure of welfare state effort is strongly conditioned by the nature of the LIS data. The LIS post tax and transfer income distribution data measure disposable cash income. No effort was made to estimate the redistributive effects of the provision of free or subsidized public goods, a dimension of the welfare state on which the social democratic welfare state is most distinctive. Thus, variations in the funding and delivery of social services have no obvious effect on the measures of reduction in inequality and post tax and transfer inequality we have calculated from the LIS data. Our measure of welfare state effort, "Taxes and Transfers", is the sum of the standard scores for total taxes as a percentage of GDP and transfer payments as a percentage of GDP (see Table 1). We standardize the two measures in order to weigh them equally. We coded the political variables, left-party government share and Christian democratic party government share, as "1" for each year that these parties were 7 See http://lisweb.ceps.lu/techdoc/variabdef.htm for a summary of LIS income variables. Distribution and Redistribution, draft 5/14/01 8 in government alone, and as a fraction of their seats in parliament of all governing parties' seats for coalition governments. Our measure of veto points created by the constitutional structure is an additive index of federalism (none, weak, strong), presidentialism (absent, present), bicameralism (absent, weak, strong), and the use of popular referenda as a normal element of the political process (absent, present). Thus, a high score indicates high dispersion of political power and the presence of multiple veto points in the political process. We considered a number of different measures of globalization: trade openness, inward and outward direct foreign investment, borrowing on international capital markets, imports from third world countries, and Quinn/Inclan measures of capital and current account controls. The specificity of the hypothesis on the effect of third world imports argued for the inclusion of this variable. For a more general measure of economic openness, we favored the control measures over the flow measures because, as Simmons (1999) and others have argued, it is the possibility of easy exit that changes the behavior of actors not variations in actual flows. To take two examples, in the absence of capital controls, (1) interest rates should equalize because capital will flow out of countries with low interest rates, and (2) domestic capital will be empowered vis à vis labor and government because it could exit were its demands not met. Thus, we selected the Quinn/Inclan measure of capital controls, in which the maximum score indicates no capital controls, as our general measure of economic openness. In fact, this measure was most strongly correlated with our inequality measures of the available globalization measures. For union density, we use union membership as a percentage of total wage and salary earners (Ebbinghaus and Visser 1992). Our industrialism measure is percent of the labor force employed in industry. The bargaining centralization measure is Iversen's measure which weighs the level at which bargaining takes place (plant and firm level, industry level, national level) by the number of workers covered by agreements at that level. A higher score indicates more centralized bargaining. We also considered two other measures of labor market institutions which Wallerstein (1999) found to be strongly related to wage dispersion, the level of wage setting and the Herfindahl index of concentration within confederations. The Iversen measure is preferable to Wallerstein's level of wage setting measure for our purposes because the Wallerstein measure combines bargaining centralization with interventions by governments to set wages, and we want to keep the effects of politics and labor market institutions separate in so far as possible. However, we did cross check our results using these measures in place of Iversen's index and they performed no better on the pre tax and transfer inequality on which we expected strong effects of labor market institutions. The operationalizations of percent of the total labor force unemployed, female labor force participation, and percent of the population under 15 are selfexplanatory. Fourteen of the eighteen large advanced industrial countries which have 8 The Alderson and Nielsen (2001) results suggest that we should also include the percentage of the population in agriculture as an independent variable. We did test this hypothesis but it did not have the hypothesized effect in our data, which do not reach as far back in time as their data. The agricultural section is very small in all of our countries by this point in time (mean = 5%). Distribution and Redistribution, draft 5/14/01 9 been democracies since World War II are included in the analysis. New Zealand and Japan are excluded as there are no LIS surveys for these countries. The one Austrian LIS survey is excluded due lack of LIS data for pre tax and transfer inequality and the one Irish LIS survey is excluded due to missing data on bargaining centralization. The average values for the dependent variables and some of the independent variables are listed by country grouped by welfare state regime in Table 2. Estimation techniques Unbalanced panel data and correlated errors We use an unbalanced panel data set with 61 observations on 14 countries, with countries providing different numbers of observations according to data availability, with a minimum of 1 and a maximum of 7 observations per country. The time span between observations is irregular, varying across countries and time points. A central problem in estimating regression models from panel data is that the assumption of independence of errors across observations is unlikely to be satisfied. As a result OLS produces incorrect standard errors for the regression coefficients (e.g., Hsiao 1986; Greene 1993). There are several strategies to deal with correlated errors in panel data. One popular approach (exemplified by the Parks method) assumes unit specific serial correlation of the errors, as in a classical time series. As pointed out by Beck and Katz (1995:635-4) the Parks method and its extensions require what Stimson (1985) calls temporally dominated time series of cross sections, i.e. data structures consisting of relatively few units observed over many equally spaced time points. The small number of time points and the unequal spacing of observations in our data set do not support estimation of an autoregressive process. Another major approach is to estimate a random effect model (REM) in which the error term contains a unit specific component that differs across units (countries) but is constant over time for a given unit. Such an error structure would arise if unmeasured unit specific causes (such as systematic measurement differences, or aspects of the history or culture of a country) affect the dependent variable in the same way at each point in time over the period of the data. The stable unit specific component implies that observations for the same unit at different time points are all correlated by the same amount Rho. The REM strategy is feasible in this situation, and it allows estimating the value of Rho. But REM requires relatively strong assumptions and may not be optimal given the small sample size. (See also We chose an estimation approach that is appropriate to an estimation situation (like the present one) in which it is not essential to measure the correlation Rho of the errors pertaining to the same unit and that necessitates minimal assumptions on the behavior of the errors. It consists in combining OLS estimation of the regression coefficients with the Huber-White (or “sandwich”) robust estimator of the standard errors. The robust estimator takes into account the correlations among errors associated with the “clustering” of observations pertaining to the same country (see the discussion in StataCorp 1999, User’s Guide pp. 256-260). As an additional check we also estimated Distribution and Redistribution, draft 5/14/01 10 the models using a variant of the generalized linear model, available in the program STATA as procedure xtgee, that is equivalent to feasible generalized least squares estimation of the REM. In the discussion of the results we report when the OLS and REM estimates are substantially different.

برای دانلود متن کامل این مقاله و بیش از 32 میلیون مقاله دیگر ابتدا ثبت نام کنید

ثبت نام

اگر عضو سایت هستید لطفا وارد حساب کاربری خود شوید

منابع مشابه

This Is My (Post) Truth, Tell Me Yours; Comment on “The Rise of Post-truth Populism in Pluralist Liberal Democracies: Challenges for Health Policy”

This is a commentary on the article ‘The rise of post-truth populism in pluralist liberal democracies: challenges for health policy.’ It critically examines two of its key concepts: populism and ‘post truth.’ This commentary argues that there are different types of populism, with unclear links to impacts, and that in some ways, ‘post-truth’ has resonances with arguments advanced in the period a...

متن کامل

Community Psychology as a Process of Citizen Participation in Health Policy; Comment on “The Rise of Post-truth Populism in Pluralist Liberal Democracies: Challenges for Health Policy”

This brief commentary discusses a recent paper by Speed and Mannion that explores “The Rise of post truth populism in liberal democracies: challenges for health policy.” It considers their assertion that through meaningful democratic engagement in health policy, some of the risks brought about by an exclusionary populist politics can be mediated. With an overview of what participation means in ...

متن کامل

The Rise of Post-truth Populism in Pluralist Liberal Democracies: Challenges for Health Policy

Recent years have witnessed the rise of populism and populist leaders, movements and policies in many pluralist liberal democracies, with Brexit and the election of Trump the two most recent high profile examples of this backlash against established political elites and the institutions that support them. This new populism is underpinned by a post-truth politics which is using social media as a...

متن کامل

The Political Foundations of Redistribution and Equality in Postindustrial Capitalist Democracies

Does the organization of business matter for redistribution and labor market equality in post-industrial democratic capitalism? Conventional welfare state analysis has given this significant question scant attention. We argue, however, that high levels of employer organization, as well as the persistence of centralized bargaining and national policy formation between these well organized employ...

متن کامل

“Stop, You’re Killing us!” An Alternative Take on Populism and Public Health; Comment on “The Rise of Post-truth Populism in Pluralist Liberal Democracies: Challenges for Health Policy”

Ewen Speed and Russell Mannion correctly identify several contours of the challenges for health policy in what it is useful to think of as a post-democratic era. I argue that the problem for public health is not populism per se, but rather the distinctive populism of the right coupled with the failure of the left to develop compelling counternarratives. Further, defences of ‘science’ must be te...

متن کامل

Populism, Exclusion, Post-truth. Some Conceptual Caveats; Comment on “The Rise of Post-truth Populism in Pluralist Liberal Democracies: Challenges for Health Policy”

In their editorial, Speed and Mannion identify two main challenges “the rise of post-truth populism” poses for health policy: the populist threat to inclusive healthcare policies, and the populist threat to well-designed health policies that draw on professional expertise and research evidence. This short comment suggests some conceptual clarifications that might help in thinking through more p...

متن کامل

ذخیره در منابع من


  با ذخیره ی این منبع در منابع من، دسترسی به آن را برای استفاده های بعدی آسان تر کنید

برای دانلود متن کامل این مقاله و بیش از 32 میلیون مقاله دیگر ابتدا ثبت نام کنید

ثبت نام

اگر عضو سایت هستید لطفا وارد حساب کاربری خود شوید

عنوان ژورنال:

دوره   شماره 

صفحات  -

تاریخ انتشار 2001